Food security and agricultural development in times of high commodity prices
Table Of Contents
Project Abstract
<p> <b>ABSTRACT</b></p><p><b></b>Efforts to promote food security must distinguish between short-term and medium-term measures,
but also between countries with agricultural potential and without such potential, argues this paper.
Furthermore, while high international food prices provide appropriate incentives for agricultural
development, it would be misguided to expect that they will automatically result in an increase of
agricultural output.
Globally, food security is both a demand-side and the supply-side challenge. High food prices
make it more difficult to address food security on the demand-side, as more and more low-income
households become unable to afford sufficient food, but at the same time, higher food prices can
provide impetus to address food security on the supply-side, as more and more farmers may find
it lucrative to increase agricultural production. However, not all countries can address both
challenges simultaneously.
In principle, a higher rate of food self-sufficiency can help to increase the food security of the local
population. But efforts to boost food production are viable only in countries that have agricultural
potential; in others such efforts bear great opportunity cost. Viable approaches to promote food
security must recognize, this paper argues, that food security is not per se dependent on a country’s
food trade balance. At the country level, food security does not depend on whether countries are
able to cover domestic food consumption through domestic food production, but whether they are
able to generate sufficient financial resources to finance necessary food imports. The same holds
true at the household level.
Hunger must be addressed through social policies, including food aid, in the short run, but it can
sustainably be addressed only through higher household incomes in the medium run. Countries that
do not have potential in agriculture will need to address food insecurity through the development
of non-agricultural sectors, which generate more, and more productive and remunerative jobs,
particularly for low-income households. By contrast, countries that have potential in agriculture
would most suitably address food insecurity through economic development that includes the
agricultural sector.
Although higher international food prices can provide appropriate incentives for agricultural
development, it should not be expected, the paper argues, that higher international food prices
will automatically result in an increase of agricultural output. While desirable, this reaction is
crucially dependent on two factors, namely (i) the pass-through of international commodity price
changes to the farm gate; and (ii) the farmers’ capacity to raise production in response. In many
developing countries, especially low-income countries, the pass-through to farm gates and the
productive capacities of farmers, is insufficient, and therefore requires appropriate policies
Abstract
Efforts to promote food security must distinguish between short-term and medium-term measures,
but also between countries with agricultural potential and without such potential, argues this paper.
Furthermore, while high international food prices provide appropriate incentives for agricultural
development, it would be misguided to expect that they will automatically result in an increase of
agricultural output.
Globally, food security is both a demand-side and the supply-side challenge. High food prices
make it more difficult to address food security on the demand-side, as more and more low-income
households become unable to afford sufficient food, but at the same time, higher food prices can
provide impetus to address food security on the supply-side, as more and more farmers may find
it lucrative to increase agricultural production. However, not all countries can address both
challenges simultaneously.
In principle, a higher rate of food self-sufficiency can help to increase the food security of the local
population. But efforts to boost food production are viable only in countries that have agricultural
potential; in others such efforts bear great opportunity cost. Viable approaches to promote food
security must recognize, this paper argues, that food security is not per se dependent on a country’s
food trade balance. At the country level, food security does not depend on whether countries are
able to cover domestic food consumption through domestic food production, but whether they are
able to generate sufficient financial resources to finance necessary food imports. The same holds
true at the household level.
Hunger must be addressed through social policies, including food aid, in the short run, but it can
sustainably be addressed only through higher household incomes in the medium run. Countries that
do not have potential in agriculture will need to address food insecurity through the development
of non-agricultural sectors, which generate more, and more productive and remunerative jobs,
particularly for low-income households. By contrast, countries that have potential in agriculture
would most suitably address food insecurity through economic development that includes the
agricultural sector.
Although higher international food prices can provide appropriate incentives for agricultural
development, it should not be expected, the paper argues, that higher international food prices
will automatically result in an increase of agricultural output. While desirable, this reaction is
crucially dependent on two factors, namely (i) the pass-through of international commodity price
changes to the farm gate; and (ii) the farmers’ capacity to raise production in response. In many
developing countries, especially low-income countries, the pass-through to farm gates and the
productive capacities of farmers, is insufficient, and therefore requires appropriate policies
<b>
</b><br></p>
Project Overview
<p>
Introduction </p><p>During the early years of their independence developing countries were exporting commodities; many
developed countries specialized in manufactures. As commodity exporters, developing countries suffered
from relatively volatile commodity prices in the short run and declining commodity prices over the long
run. On the other hand, manufactured prices tended to increase. These developments were a major concern
for developing countries and subsequently became an important focus of UNCTAD’s work. UNCTAD’s
first Secretary-General, Raul Prebisch, as well as Hans Singer, have highlighted the negative implications
of volatile and declining terms of trade for developing countries (Prebisch, 1960; Singer, 1950).
Since the turn of the millennium however many commodity prices, including the prices of many agricultural
produce, have increased substantially, while at the same time many manufactured prices, especially the
prices of low-tech and low value added manufactures, have declined, effectively improving the terms
of trade for the developing countries that continue to depend on commodity exports.1
This development
prompted the Trade and Development Report 2005 (UNCTAD, 2005) to examine the question whether
the reversal in barter terms of trade is likely to be a lasting phenomenon, which provides a historical
opportunity for developing countries and encourages a rethinking of the classical development strategies
that focused on promoting a gradual graduation from a commodity-dependent economy and an increasing
specialization in manufactures.
However, as the group of developing countries has become increasingly diverse during the past decades,
there is no simple and uniform answer to this question. On the one side of the spectrum are relatively
successful developing countries, especially in East and South-East Asia, which have increased their
specialization in basic manufactures; on the other are many low-income countries, especially in Africa,
which have maintained a strong specialization in primary commodities. Contrary to the latter, the former
are negatively affected by the improving barter terms of trade. However, as highlighted by the Trade and
Development Report 2005, countries in East and South-East Asia have more than compensated for declining
unit values of their exports through a more than proportionate increase of their export volumes, resulting
in a significant increase of their income terms of trade. By contrast, many countries in Africa have not
been able to significantly increase their export volumes, despite increasing unit values of their exports,
and have therefore seen only a small improvement of their purchasing power of exports. How economies
react to changing barter terms of trade depends on whether the change of international commodity prices
translates into a change of local producer prices, and whether economies have the productive capacities
to react to such price changes.</p><p> Although the global financial crisis and economic slowdown have led to a marked decline of commodity
prices since their peak in mid-2008, commodity prices are expected to remain elevated compared with
historical trends, and especially compared with the late 1990s. And indeed many commodity prices have
begun to rise again in recent months. Against this backdrop, this paper examines whether international
commodity price hikes are a threat or an opportunity for developing countries. Such price hikes can, on
the one hand, lead to rising food prices and undermine food security; but they can, on the other hand,
also lead to rising farm gate prices and stimulate agricultural production. To evaluate the threats and
opportunities that arise from higher levels of international food prices, this paper examines the pass-through
of international food prices to both consumers and producers. Section B of this paper describes the recent
increase of commodity prices; section C focuses on effects of commodity price hikes on consumers and
producers; section D outlines the challenge of agricultural development in developing countries; and
section E derives implications for policymakers.
<br></p><p>
The paper concludes that the prospect of high and sustained commodity prices provides indeed a historical
opportunity for some of the poorest developing countries, many of which continue to be characterized
by a strong dependence on commodities, to develop and benefit from the commodity economy. Yet, to
minimize associated threats and size upon this opportunity is not an automatic process. To minimize threats,
requires active social policies; to size opportunities demands active economic policies. The successful
development of the agricultural sector ultimately necessitates that higher commodity prices are passed
through to the farm gate (a question of appropriate incentives) and that farmers are capable of reacting
to higher commodity prices (a question of productive capacities). To raise agricultural production and
productivity, demands that available factors of production be more effectively and fully utilized, and
that the linkages between the different economic sectors be strengthened. This critically depends on
entrepreneurial capabilities, but also appropriate business support institutions and a functioning banking
sector, which supplies credit that is suitable for investments in the real economy (Gore and Herrmann,
2008; UNCTAD, 2008a). Furthermore, developing countries must find ways to cope with short-term
adjustment costs, including rising food prices which can undermine food security
<br></p>