INFLUENCE OF PRICES ON MARKET PARTICIPATION DECISIONS OF INDIGENOUS POULTRY FARMERS IN FOUR DISTRICTS OF EASTERN PROVINCE, KENYA
Table Of Contents
Project Abstract
<p> <b>ABSTRACT</b> </p><p>Over 70% of the domesticated birds in Kenya are indigenous chicken (IC) providing meat
and table eggs. They are frequently raised through the free range, backyard production
system. Small flock sizes are characteristic of this production system and often, sales are
mainly at the farmgate. Although IC production possesses enormous potential at livelihood
improvement, marketing systems are undefined and variable. The influence of prices on
market engagement has frequently been assumed. A study of 68 farmers conducted in
Machakos, Kibwezi, Nzaui and Mwala District in 2008 revealed that 70% of all IC sales
were conducted at the farmgate while only 19% of the sales were at the local market. This
study also investigates the probability of market participation by employing a binary logistic
regression model. The results suggests that while farmers complain of poor farm gate prices
for indigenous chicken offered by middlemen, low volumes are an important drawback to
market participation.
Keywords Market, Price, Indigenous chicken, Farm-gate
<br></p>
Project Overview
<p><b>1.0 INTRODUCTION </b></p><p><b>1.1 BACKGROUND OF THE STUDY</b></p><p>There are an estimated 29 million birds in Kenya with Indigenous Chicken (IC) being
70% of this number. Indigenous poultry production in Kenya is an important activity for 75%
of the Kenyan population and these birds are mostly kept for domestic consumption and sale.
The numbers kept vary with location but are largely reared under the free range system which
is estimated to be more profitable (Menge, Kosgey & Kahi, 2007) than keeping indigenous
poultry under confinement. However, these birds need extra feed to supplement that obtained
from their scavenging activity (Kingori, Tuitoek, Muiruri, Wachira & Birech, 2007). Usually,
these flocks are small and external inputs few (Okitoi, Udo, Mukisira, De Jong & Kwakkel,
2006). For instance, Sørensen (2007) puts the flock sizes in Makueni at between 20-30, while
for Western province they are estimated as between 7-10 birds (Waithaka, Nyangaga, Staal,
Wokabi, Njubi, Muriuki, et.al,. 2002) while Okitoi et.al., (2006) put this figure at 10-20 birds.
These figures are against a national average of 13 birds per household (Nyaga, 2007). In
Uganda, the size varies anywhere between 17-22 birds (Illango, Etoori, Olupot & Mabonga,
2002; Ssewannyana, Onyait, Ogwal & Masaba, 2006) while in Morocco, these are 11 chicken
per household (Benabdeljelil, Arfaoui & Johnston, 2001) and between 15-20 birds in
Botswana (Badubi, Rakereng & Marumo, 2006). IC in Nigeria, as in many parts of Africa are
an important income source especially for rural women (Alabi, Esobhawan & Aruna, 2006,
Akinola & George, 2008). Small flock sizes may however not be very attractive especially in
terms of market efficiency as has been reported in Malawi where farmers’ market
participation decision is not significantly influenced by prices but is ad hoc depending on the
farmers needs at any particular point in time (Gausi, Safalaoh, Banda & Ng'ong'ola, 2004).
The marketing system for indigenous birds in Kenya is described as unorganised,
weak and indeterminate (Mathuva 2005, Munyasi, Nzioka, Kabiru, Wachira, Mwangi,
Kaguthi et.al., 2009). In Uganda, many farmers do not assess market conditions before
embarking on production (Alum, Kanzikwera & Sanginga, 2007) a scenario that is probably
replicated in Kenya.</p><p> This may partly explain why production is still low despite the existence
of an unmet demand for poultry meat estimated at 12.4kg per adult equivalent in the urban
areas (Gamba, Kariuki & Gathigi, 2005) and projected to grow to 29,600MT by 2014
(Muthee, 2006). It would be expected that with properly functioning markets, farmers should
scale production and therefore supply, to reflect market trends.
<br></p><p>
However, supply will be responsive only after farmers make the decision to
participate in the market, decisions conditioned by several factors. There are very few
empirical studies showing the association between these indices and the decision to sell IC in
particular since many farmers sell to avoid major losses from disease. For the IC sector, two
market channels are available to farmers viz, at the farmgate, or at the market. IC prices are
usually spot prices with prices varying by season, chicken sex, size and trader (Munyasi et.al,
2009), but rarely are the birds weighed just as reported for many African countries (Guèye,
2001). Traders usually buy IC from farmers in the rural markets and assemble these for
subsequent sale in larger urban markets. A Value Chain analysis for IC in Kilifi and Kwale
reports the main reasons cited for the decision by farmers to sell are the need to offload in
anticipation of disease outbreaks and to earn some income to cater for household
requirements. The major disease causing mortalities in flocks is New Castle Disease (NCD).
In Western Kenya, reducing mortality in chicken through NCD vaccination by 1% was
shown to increase offtake by 0.11% (Okitoi, et.al, 2006). In Uganda, IC flock sizes were
shown to increase by 195% following crossbreeding and NCD vaccinations, the latter
reducing mortalities by 86% (Ssewannyana, et.al., 2006).
<br></p><p>
In Kenya, many IC farmers complain of low profits as they point an accusing finger
towards exploitative middlemen (Nyange, 2000). Prices offered to IC farmers are low at
about 18% of the terminal price in Coastal Kenya while in other countries IC farmers appear
to receive fairly higher returns (see for instance Mlozi, Kakengi, Minga, Mtambo & Olsen,
2003, Gondwe, Wollny & Kaumbata, 2005).
Munyasi et.al. (2009) report disease and price fluctuations in the larger Machakos and
Makueni districts to be the major challenges in the marketing of IC from the perspective of
traders. With an uncertain price structure, it is not clear whether farmers on the other hand
respond to market information. This paper therefore explores the prices offered farmers for
IC and distance to markets and their influence on the decision to participate in the market by
poultry farmers.
<br></p><p><b>1.2 MATERIALS AND METHODS</b></p><p><b> 1.2.1 Data collection and general description of study area </b></p><p>To study these relationships, we use baseline data collected from farmers; all
members of IC common interest groups (CIGs) who received training from service providers
on main aspects of poultry management viz; housing, feeding, disease control and marketing
between August and September 2008. The farmers were located in 8 divisions of Machakos,
Mwala, Nzaui and Kibwezi Districts (which were carved from the larger Machakos and
Makueni districts) and they included Kalama, Kibwezi, Makindu, Matiliku, Mbitini, Mulala,
Nguu and Yathui divisions. Farmers to be interviewed were selected randomly from their
respective CIGs from membership lists, provided that the CIGs had requested for IC technical
services, had registration certificates and were composed of at least 20-50 members. At least
10% of the farmers from each CIG were interviewed. The groups had significantly fewer
male members (mean of 5) compared to a mean of 22 female members and seven out of the
29 CIGs were solely made up of female members. The oldest CIG was registered in 1996
with the latest registrations being those of 2008. A questionnaire was designed to gather
periodic data on IC management as well as sales of IC, data necessary to monitor posttraining progress in IC management among this group of farmers. During the first week of
December 2008, a total of 68 farmers were interviewed from where cross-sectional recall (3
month period in reference to September-November) data on IC sales and prices in addition to
other IC management practices were gathered. The questionnaire requested farmers to recall
how many birds they had sold, where this sale had occurred and prices received from the
sales.<br></p><p>1.3 <b>THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL FRAMEWORK</b></p><p>Some theoretical and empirical contributions explaining market behaviour include
Barnum & Squire (1979), Singh, Squire & Strauss (1986), Sadoulet and de Janvry (1995).
These assume properly functioning factor and product markets. In semi-subsistence situations
much of which characterize small scale producers, production and consumption decisions are
not separable and market participation takes place when a household’s shadow price is lower
than the market price with an allowance for transaction costs. Similar approaches have
focused on explaining such decision processes in technology adoption studies. In the market
participation literature, the decision about market participation is a two-stage process, the first
being the decision to participate while a related decision on how much market involvement
comes next in that sequence. Some applications of these procedures in market participation
analysis include Key, Sadoulet & de Janvry (2000), Bellemare & Barrett (2006). Studies have
modelled this decision as being influenced by both on and off-farm level factors (Montshwe,
Jooste & Alemu, 2004, Uchezuba, Moshabele & Digopo 2009). Recent studies have extended
the approach to consider farmer preference for different aspects of the marketing systems
themselves (Abdulai & Birachi, 2008, Blandon, Henson & Islam, 2009).
In our study, it is hypothesised that since farmers make sale decisions sequentially
(Bellemare & Barrett, 2006), then they first make the decision to sell (SELL=1) after which
the decision on where to sell and how many birds to sell (SOLD) given prices at the chosen
market is made. In this paper, we are concerned with the first decision, that of market
participation. The underlying determinants (xi) of these separate decisions are assumed to be
identical (Jha and Hojjati, 1994) and include the farmer’s initial endowment (flock size),
distance to the chosen market (a dimension of transaction cost) and the price of a bird at the
market. As members of CIGs, it is assumed that these farmers are not autarkic and further,
that market participation involves sales of IC and not purchases. Observed sale prices are
somewhere above the reservation price since with spot markets such as those characterizing
IC, sellers do not have an exact map of prices offered but may only have a reservation price
below which a sale agreement is not made. Other factors, such as the overall incentive
environment, aggregate demand situation that are likely to shift the market response curve are
assumed fixed in the short run, and their effects cannot be deciphered from this data set. In
sum therefore, only prices and market distance are available for analysis in this dataset. To
estimate the influence of these variables on the decision of farmers to sell IC, the model;
<br></p><p>
Prob (SELL=1) = 1 – F(-γX),……..(i) </p><p>for the probability of engaging in a sale (SELL=1) is estimated. Due to limitations in the
dataset, in the absence of flock sizes [FZt-1] at period t-1 (i.e. when sale decision was made),
we employ a rather contestable but simplifying assumption. A summation of reported sales
(SOLD) and current flock size FZt1 will yield the situation at t-1 when the sale decision was
made i.e. (FZt-1= SOLD + FZt). This result is what we use as the flock size in the regression.
Further, prices (p) are assumed to be fixed in time i.e. pt-1 = pt
. In many applications, it is
assumed that F is either the cumulative normal (probit model) or the cumulative logistic
distribution function (logit model) but in practice, there usually is no prior knowledge to
justify this distributional assumption (Gerfin, 1996). The logistic regression approach is a
powerful, convenient and flexible technique that can be used to describe the relationship of
several independent variables to a dichotomous dependent variable (in this case SELL). Due
to its mathematical convenience, the logistic regression has been used extensively (Greene,
2007). The probability of a result being in one of two responses is modeled as a function of
the level of one or more explanatory variables. Thus, the probability of a farmer selling IC
(probability SELL=1) is modeled as a function of prices and distance to the nearest market.
<br></p><p>
From equation ii above, the subscript j is the response category out of k categories (SELL=1
or SELL=0), i denotes individual farmers (1, 2, 3, 4…, n=68), ï¦ is the conditional probability,
αo is the coefficient of the constant term, βj is the coefficient of the independent variable, Xij
is a matrix of observed values and εi is a matrix of unobserved random effects.
<br></p><p>
Rearranging (ii) the logistic regression can be manipulated to calculate the conditional
probabilities from (iii) above where e is the base of the natural logarithm (≈2.718).
<br></p><p><b>1.4 DATA ANALYSIS </b></p><p>These estimations are implemented by invoking the proc logistic procedure in SAS.
For most applications with discrete data, proc logistic is the preferred choice and it fits binary
response or proportional odds models, provides a number of model-selection methods for
identifying important prognostic variables from a large number of candidate variables, and
computes regression diagnostic statistics (So, 1999). Unlike in classical regression analysis,
the parameters from the logistic regression are not easy to interpret. Hence, to compute
marginal effects, one can evaluate the expressions at the sample means of the data or evaluate
the marginal effects at every observation and use the sample average of the individual
marginal effects (Greene, 2007). For a continuous explanatory variable, x, e(βx) represents
the change in odds for a unit increase in x (Schlotzhauer, 1993). The estimated empirical
model is of the form SELL = f(FZ, Distance, Price) and is estimated by maximum likelihood.
One of the farmers was found to be reporting information regarding exotic broilers and this
observation was dropped from the analysis.
<br></p>